The Triple Helix as a Model for Innovation Studies
(Conference Report), Science & Public Policy Vol. 25(3) (1998) 195-203
Loet Leydesdorff & Henry Etzkowitz *
The Second Conference on the Triple Helix of University-Industry-Government Relations focused on "the future location of research." In this report, the Triple Helix thesis is developed into a recursive model of how an overlay of communications operates on the underlying institutions. Market selections, innovative dynamics, and network controls provide different codes of communication at the global level. Local translations at the interfaces induce adaptation mechanisms in the institutional arrangements. While two dynamics tend to coevolve into trajectories, a regime of transitions emerges when trajectories can be recombined. The emerging hyper-networks are expected to be in flux. Institutions can then be flexible in temporarily assuming roles of other partners. Niche management and human capital management become crucial.
Introduction
The second international "Triple Helix" conference on university-industry-government relations brought together researchers, practitioners, and policy analysts from the three institutional spheres to the State University of New York at Purchase. More than 160 delegates came from 30 countries in Europe, Asia, and North and South America. The largest contingents were from the U.S. (50), Brazil (18), and The Netherlands (8). Among the other countries represented were Romania, Sweden, Germany, New Zealand, Japan, Norway, Uruguay, France, Mexico, Italy, and Russia.
The theme of the conference was "The Future Location of Research." Ninety
papers were presented, and three dozen panelists analyzed the conference
theme at multi-national, national, regional, and local levels during the
four-day meeting. Following upon the initial meeting (Amsterdam 1996; Leydesdorff
& Etzkowitz 1996) which highlighted European Union S&T policies,
special sessions with U.S. science policy officials such as Dr. Arthur
Bienenstock, Director of the Science Division of the Office of Science
and Technology Policy (OSTP) in the Executive Office of the President,
exemplified the U.S. location of this conference.
The Theme of the Conference
How does "the future location of research" relate to the Triple Helix program of research? Why have some regions (such as metropolitan New York) and nations (such as Sweden) with significant R&D resources lagged behind in creating high-tech industries, and how can they best utilize these resources to catch up and forge ahead? How do the network perspectives of the Triple Helix relate to empirical materials collected in local practices, and how can these materials inform theoretical specification?
Local conditions provide the resources on which one has to operate in a network mode. Interactions at the network level generate mutual expectations that feed back on the institutional arrangements; for example, by allowing for strategic alliances. The institutional transformations themselves coevolve with the development of technologies and markets at the global level (Nelson 1994). The knowledge base of the economy is thus increasingly a part of the infrastructure of society. There is also recognition of the necessity for a proactive, but not totalizing role for the state in science, technology, and innovation policies. In addition to facilitating structural adjustments (Freeman & Perez 1988) governments can function to stimulating network development among nation states and across institutional boundaries.
The functional roles of the bureaucracy have to be matched with the need for political direction and choice. For example, the series of Framework Programs of the European Union has increasingly focused on so-called Research, Technology, and Development (`RTD') Networks. Where national levels are for political reasons not able to intervene like as the U.S.A., other levels like international or subnational ones provide new opportunities for the specific organization of these interfaces (Gulbrandsen & Etzkowitz 1998; cf. Van der Belt & Rip 1987). Solutions anticipate problems, but the institutional layer feeds back selectively on the range of possible solutions.
Thus, one plenary session focused on the issue of whether the emerging entrepreneurial university, through its involvement with intellectual property rights, threatens open scientific communication. This issue continues to be debated, especially in the U.S.A., where the Bay/Dohle Act of 1980 requires U.S. universities to put into use the intellectual property rights generated from their federally funded research. The various forms this use has taken include the filing of patent applications and the formation of new firms based upon rights that the law transferred from the federal government to the universities.
Richard R. Nelson (Columbia University, U.S.A.) argued in his keynote speech that such a policy has detrimental effects on scientific communication, and that the law should be revised if not repealed. He held that a new set of norms has emerged which encourage secrecy rather than publication, since the research process has been infused with extra-scientific considerations. Moreover, the translation of research into property adds unnecessary "transaction costs" to the transfer of knowledge from academia to industry, an objective that, he argued, could be accomplished more expeditiously through publication in open scientific literature.
Professor Nelson's arguments opened up a wide ranging debate among the panelists and the audience that will likely extend beyond the conference. One panelist noted that patenting is itself a form of publication, requiring perhaps even more disclosure of the technical detail necessary for replication than an academic paper. Another panelist, a university Vice President for Research, noted that unversities purchase far more from industry than vice-versa. Indeed, a trade imbalance may be said to exist, one that the sale of intellectual property rights has hardly redressed.
Nevertheless, these issues are all subsidiary to the larger question
of the appropriate role of the university in society. Should the university
be an "ivory tower" of independent reflection, or a generator of economic
wealth, or somehow play both of these roles, which it clearly does to one
degree or another in different empirical instances? In practice, the debate
is over where to place emphasis. It is difficult to prescribe solutions
to these issues at a translocal level because there are no single solutions.
Trade-offs have to be elaborated, codified, and sometimes suspended or
perhaps abolished. To the extent that one is able to communicate and to
recodify with increasing complexity and precision, one will be able to
move technological innovation forward. Decisions made on the basis of more
diverse knowledge and informed insights are changing the landscape of opportunities.
What is a Triple Helix ?
In recent years, a number of concepts have been proposed for modeling the transformation processes in university-industry-government relations. For example, national systems of innovation (Lundvall 1992; Nelson 1993) have been compared with regional systems (e.g., Gulbrandsen 1997; Gebhardt 1997; De Castro et al. 1998). From the network perspective, the governance level can be considered as a variable. Gibbons et al. (1994) noted that innovation is a fuzzy process: it requires the blurring of boundaries in what these authors have called `Mode 2' of the production of scientific knowledge. There was considerable debate at the meeting not only over the empirical basis of the Triple Helix, but also about its normative implications. At least three main forms of the Triple Helix model were identified.
In Triple Helix I the three spheres are defined institutionally (university, industry, and government). Interaction across otherwise defended boundaries is mediated by organizations such as industrial liaison, technology transfer, and contract offices. In Triple Helix II the helices are defined as different communication systems consisting of the operation of markets, technological innovations ("upsetting the movement towards equilibrium"; Nelson & Winter 1982), and control at the interfaces (Leydesdorff 1997). The interfaces among these different functions operate in a distributed mode that produce potentially new forms of communication as in a sustained technology transfer interface or in the case of patent legislation.
In Triple Helix III the institutional spheres of university, industry, and government, in addition to performing their traditional functions, each assume the roles of the others, with universities creating an industrial penumbra, or performing a quasi-governmental role as a regional or local innovation organizer (e.g., Pires & Castro 1997; Gulbrandsen 1997). The industrial R&D laboratory can be considered as a historical example of the internalization of such organizational complexity (Noble 1977). An intermediate level of agencies and small enterprises is typical of the "post-modern" research system (Rip & Van der Meulen 1996).
The model is recursive, since Triple Helix II tends to produce an inner core of communicative overlaps among the institutions of Triple Helix I that can be institutionalized to a greater or lesser degree. However, the different versions of the Tripe Helix posit different types of intersections among the institutional spheres with significant implications for both theory and practice.
The institutionally defined Triple Helix is premised upon separate academic, industrial, and governmental spheres and the "knowledge flows" among them. Transfer is no longer considered as a linear process from an origin to an application. Historical patterns of interaction can be reconstructed.
While "knowledge flows," tracked by scientometrics, are an important constituent of science-based economic growth, more intensive relations of increasing complexity have emerged in the course of the capitalization of knowledge. The emerging Triple Helix III is based upon a complex set of organizational ties among overlapping spheres that increasingly elide the boundaries between them (Etzkowitz et al. 1998a). In addition to linkages among institutional spheres, each sphere is increasingly able to assume the role of another. Thus, universities take on entrepreneurial tasks such as marketing knowledge and creating companies, while firms develop an academic dimension, sharing knowledge among each other and training employees at ever higher skill levels.
Triple Helix II adds an overlay of communications to the network that has a dynamics of its own. In addition to analysis in terms of its composition and generation, one can focus on the resulting feedback as another subdynamics (Hull et al. 1998). From the evolutionary perspective, historical analysis ("following the actors"; Latour 1987) is useful as far as one can reconstruct on the basis of current understanding, how the actors involved had to learn to overcome the prevailing contingencies. Evolutionary models do not focus on the historical contexts per se, but on the operation of the emerging systems of innovation. Thus, the emphasis shifts from construction in terms of agency to the constructed systems in terms of their innovativeness (Luhmann 1990).
The different versions of the Triple Helix model can be at odds with each other both in theory and practice. Conflicts over the definition of "conflicts of interests" among persons with dual institutional roles provide a strategic research site to assess these changes in perspective. Competing hypotheses derived from different versions of the Triple Helix can be explored through formal modelling and appreciated through institutional analysis. In the longer-term research program the outcomes of model studies have to be evaluated as hypotheses and heuristics, while the case studies inform the modelling efforts about contingencies and boundary conditions.
This recursive model of the Triple Helix enables us to relate the various perspectives. Evolutionary pressures induce differentiation in all relevant subsystems. Innovation can then be considered as the reflexive recombination of specific contexts, for example, between a technological option and a market perspective. The specification of these different contexts requires theorizing. For the purpose of innovation, the perspectives have to be translated into each other, for example, in terms of a strategic plan. The translation potentially reinforces the research process by raising new questions, for example, by comparing across different contexts, yet with reference to emerging phenomena.
In other words, the Triple Helix model is sufficiently complex to encompass
the different perspectives of participant-observers (e.g., case histories)
and, from an analytical perspective, to guide us heuristically in searching
for options emerging from the interactions. For example, one is able to
distinguish between a specific configuration of university-industry-government
relations and the transformation of the infrastructure in a knowledge-intensive
economy. The systems of reference are different: Which evolutionary forces
drive the transformations? What stabilizes the institutions? Theoretical
analysis reflects on these distinctions with the aim of providing the participants
in the respective discourses with windows that will enable them to explore
new combinations.
The Triple Helix: Metaphor, Model, Reality?
The complex system of a Triple Helix depends as a regime of transition on the local trajectories which can be observed (Leydesdorff & Etzkowitz 1996; Etzkowitz & Leydesdorff 1997). One witnesses the institutional dynamics between industries, governments, and universities. The dimensions of government, industry, and higher education tend to be reproduced because they continue to serve different functions. The institutions embody the value systems or the codes of these functions.
New codes of communication are being developed at all the interfaces. For example, science is no longer valued only as a quest for truth, but also from the perspective of utilization; legal systems are developed with the aim of supporting innovative processes; industries are transformed and restructured both from the perspective of control and from the perspective of adaptation to new technological options. The institutions are involved in the transitions that they cause by their interactions.
Two discussions threaded through the meeting: one empirical, the other normative. The empirical debate raged over the question of whether universites (or the public research sector), government, and industry were sufficient components of a model to explain the emerging trends. Joske Bunders (Free University, Amsterdam) suggested that NGOs (non-governmental organizations) have played a key role in technology transfer, especially in developing countries. In her research on third-world peasants (e.g., Bunders and Broerse 1998), she found that NGO's were able to influence how technology was introduced into their societies through self-organization and alliances with first-world social movements.
In our opinion, the Triple Helix is mainly a model for analyzing innovation in a knowledge-based economy. This model accounts for the phenomenon of emergence, that is, it helps us to understand how the innovation system is based on expectations. While the complex phenomenon of innovation remains the explanandum, different theories provide us with a varitey of explanans. More than a single explanation is expected because different perspectives are useful. To take an the evolutionary metaphor, the perspectives can be considered as the "genotypes" that reflect on specific interactions within and among the helices, while the complex dynamics of innovation are "phenotypical," that is, beyond the control of any given perspectives (Langton 1989; Leydesdorff 1998).
In contrast to biological evolution, the "genes" are not given, but constructed in the social, technical, and economic evolution of modern societies with their tendency to transform themselves and their interactions operationally by rearranging their configurations. In a new regime, the system is reconstructed from a set of its own previous states, including the natural environment and society's communal roots. Thus, technology celebrates community as a social achievement, including its ongoing redefinition of "nature" and "culture".
The enterprise is risky. As Marx noted, "alienation" is the dark side of the enlightenment process. The reconstructive transformation of nature can lead to the destruction of resources that are vital to the reproduction of the system. But there is no single "best practice." At theoretical levels, one is able to simplify the reconstruction by taking for example, the national state, the discipline, or the enterprise as a unit of analysis. Analyses of innovations in terms of national systems, major technological waves, or industries, however, fail to understand innovation in terms of the interactive results among these institutionalized spheres. Interaction presumes communication among differently coded value systems, including the risk of potential conflicts.
One example of the transformations implied was presented to the conference audience by Lucio Biggiero, with his analysis of the Italian Districts from an evolutionary perspective. The Italian Districts have been widely studied because of their economic potential. Biggiero (1998) proposes to study them as hyper-networks: because of the multitude of formal and informal links between agents in these networks, niches can be maintained with extremely high problem-solving capacities. A crucial factor is the maintenance of trust in cross-institutional relations in the face of potential conflicts (Ferraro & Borroi 1998).
Many of us may recognize the best of our own institutions as hyper-networks. While one complains about the disappearance of reliable structures, the fluidities enable us to solve problems and also to approach problems from a new angle. Most changes, of course, are not innovative in the economically relevant sense of the term. The recombinations provide the variation. The Internet has taught us to play with options as variation that enables us to envisage what actually occurs as one possible event among many possible occurrences. As we proceed in this "virtual reality," the emerging structure begins to feed back on our "real" relations. This experience is prototypical for the regime change the world is nowadays experiencing. The virtual dimension does not dissolve the "real" one, yet it changes our perspective on it (Nowak and Grantham 1998).
The hyper-network reveals new recombinations as feasible and meaningful.
But one has to be able to follow up locally on these global options. One
important step, however, is to recognize the specificity of the closed
shop in which one tends to live. Whether this is a "national system", the
problems on the agenda from a current crisis, the framework of an established
discipline, or the fight for recognition of a specific transfer agency,
there is always a world beyond. By envisaging new dimensions to the problem,
one enlarges one's analytical scope.
"Global" versus "local"
Future developments are expected to be the outcomes of changes in the local contingencies and their relevant environments. Global developments induce local dynamics, and local recombinations constitute the variation for higher-order systems. The contextual changes can be perceived reflexively from the perspective of local institutions. The markets and the laboratories select by using their respective codes, that is, in terms of prices and performance. "The local" and "the global" are thus important specifications for using a Triple Helix model.
In addition to their direct policy relevance (for example, for reasons of evaluation), case studies inform us about new recombinations and emerging institutional structures. These innovations reflect and anticipate on adaptation to knowledge-intensive developments. How are the contingencies communicated and optimalized so that local advantages can be exploited as in niches? These issues couple the Triple Helix model to policy agendas as in the case of regional development, university-based incubator activities and SMEs, the local organization of new departments which cross institutional boundaries, etc.
The institutional dynamics are analyzed in terms of the coupling which they provide to global developments. In many parts of the world, a continuous "disorganization" of existing institutional boundaries has been signalled (Turpin & Garrett-Jones 1997). While from a local perspective, this may sometimes be felt as discouraging, theorizing provides us with heuristics for assessing the multitude of possibilities that the dynamics generate. Here the evolutionary dimension of the model steps in: the disturbances generate variation which tests the existing lock-ins for other potentially emerging recombinations.
What precisely is evolving in these interactions? Authors from economics have tended to take the firm or the industry as their implied unit of analysis (Andersen 1994). Historians have often focused on technologies or on the development of the university as an indicator of developments in the knowledge infrastructure. All these units are continuously developing within a larger system; borderlines are transgressed and coevolutions are generated in the various processes of mutual shapings. This dynamics becomes complex when a trilateral overlay of interactions among the recurrent bi-lateral interactions provides options for even more complex forms of stabilization. Globalization or "the transition to Mode 2" are thus a consequence of increasing network relations, not a cause (Leydesdorff 1997).
First, the recursive operation of the institutions has allowed for the stabilization of mutual interactions between institutions (e.g., corporations) and technologies along trajectories (Nelson 1994). The implied trade-offs allow for accommodation to options emerging from fuzzy processes at the interfaces (Dosi 1982). The multinational corporation, for example, has deliberately exploited the differences among national systems. Additionally, a diversified corporation is to a certain extent able to capitalize on differences in the life-cycles among technologies (Abernathy & Utterback 1978). The state can analogously be locked into technologies, as in the case of energy policies (McKelvey 1997), or the state and the economy can be locked into each other, as in the Soviet system.
When the levels of control in a third dimension are distributed, options at other levels may prevail either in the international arena or locally in a given region. For example, a network at the European level provides all the partners with options that cannot be grasped at the respective national levels. Taking the example of the Airbus development in civil aviation, Koen Frenken (INRA, Grenoble) explained in his paper how the addition of another layer to Kauffman's (1993) NK-models enables us to understand why the European dimension allowed for innovation in this industry. The existing lock-ins in the respective national systems could be both maintained and recombined.
The new layers of networking induce adaptation mechanisms within the carrying units. An academic revolution is one of the consequences: most universities nowadays use their R&D potential for economic as well as scientific functions. Internally, the transfer of resources within the university from one function to another is to be legitimated in terms of positive feedbacks (Etzkowitz 1994). The new functions require additional codes of communication, to be developed in an intermediary layer of S&T policy networks (Rip & Van der Meulen 1996). Inventions of "rules of thumb" that allow for flexible applications may help to solve conflicts of interest in the public sector and develop standard practices, particularly in relation to intellectual property rights. In other cases, formalization and even legislation may be needed to secure a new environment (Berneman & Denis 1998).
Corporations which previously had to develop a technostructure within their organizations (Galbraith 1967), have now developed an interface with public institutions in response to the new regulatory regimes of environmental and other (knowledge-intensive) legislation. Randolph Guschl, Director of Corporate Technology Transfer at DuPont Central R&D, noted that DuPont's expenditure on external technology resources increased from US$20 MM in 1993 to over US$45 MM in 1995, and this budget is still increasing. Another DuPont representative gave an example of R&D outsourcing to academic researchers in India. Instead of the company having to carry the entire cost of a group internally, an external group can integrate work for DuPont into a portfolio of related projects, with lower personnel and infrastructure costs.
Frances Via (Director for Contract Research, AKZO-Nobel Corporation,
U.S.A.) supported the DuPont thesis with examples of how corporations are
able to meet a business need faster, more cheaply, and with a better technology
by leveraging external technology sources. As Guschl noted, "There are
better ways to find partners than to go back to your thesis advisor of
twenty years ago." DuPont asks its scientists to come with three options
before making a commitment to an external supplier. This increased focus
on identifying potential research providers reflects changes in the corporation,
from internally producing its own R&D to drawing more on external sources.
It also reflected in a new focus on licensing and spinning out internally
developed technology deemed irrelevant to existing or projected business
goals.
A Regime of Transitions
Knowledge-intensity induces differentiation between a strategic level (a discourse about the questions "what and why?") and an operational level ("how?") in the organizations involved (Chandler 1962; Galbraith & Nathanson 1978). Both levels can be made relevant for specific forms of collaboration. The dynamics of the uncertainties involved, however, do not allow for rigidly fixed boundaries. Participants at one level of networking can use collaborations or boundaries at other levels as resources. Conflicts have to be addressed and elaborated into (perhaps provisional) codifications.
The established systems try to retain their contributions by reproducing themselves. Thus, the network is expected to contain tendencies toward both integration and differentiation. Whereas each co-evolution exhibits a tendency towards "mutual shaping" and thus stability along a trajectory, the complex dynamics of a Triple Helix allows for reshaping of the trajectories on which the next-order system recursively has to build.
The capacity of relevant participants to handle the complexity of the implied communications, is then the evolving unit. Adelaide Baeta discussed the learning capacity of technology transfer in the Brazilian context (Baeta 1998). Herbert Fusfeld, former President of the Industrial Research Institute (IRI) and Director Emeritus of the Center for Science and Technology Policy at Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute, noted how the meaning of technology transfer has evolved, from how R&D results are moved from central laboratories of companies to their operating divisions, from developed to developing countries, and from outside the company into the company.
Not only the substance of the communications develop, but also their codes. By translating between codes, translators communicate reflexively about communications at the interfaces. While heretofore institutional and functional differentiations have tended to correspond as in a division of labour, one now may use the one differentiation to reorganize the other. The coordination mechanisms of society have thus become further differentiated. Strategic communications open new windows by combining perspectives, while the institutional dynamics adapt selectively, as the retention mechanism. When three uncertainties operate upon each other, as among markets, sciences, and control, new combinations enable the survival of niches which are superior to the `natural' fits, yet unexpectedly and from a global perspective. Niche management and human capital management are core objectives of this complex dynamics (Tong 1996).
More than any other technology, the Internet has been paradigmatic for a global transition in the communication structure beyond the control of corporations and/or national governments. From this perspective, "national systems of innovation" are still relevant, but only as one dynamic among other subdynamics of the complex system. "User interfaces" and "networks of innovation" can be relevant for the further development of a regional university, but so are the traditional disciplines. The different interfaces codify along other axes. The one dynamic replaces the other only to a certain extent and perhaps only provisionally; otherwise, the new dimensions of communication constitute additional layers (Leydesdorff & Van den Besselaar 1997).
The emerging mix of opportunities are continuously assessed, and agreements
and disagreements about the best guesses can then be codified and communicated.
In this knowledge-intensive enterprise one is able to restructure continuously
the future location of research. A theoretically informed exchange of examples
and ideas is needed, since further learning requires reaching beyond established
boundaries among domains. Manabu Eto (MITI, Japan), for example, reported
on a major conclusion of an evaluation study of collaborative projects
in Japan: too much competition among otherwise equivalent partners in one
of the dimensions can be a disturbing factor in the collaboration (Eto
1998). One needs differences to create new perspectives. Each partner,
for example, has to be forced to explain what s/he means when using jargon
and abbreviations.
Models and policies of innovation
Among the participants we observed an increasing consensus that there is no single "best practice." Common themes, such as differences in funding mechanisms and their structuring effects on exchange mechanisms, brought a wide range of interests among delegates into focus in plenary sessions, while the rest of the conference was mainly organized in parallel streams. The focus, however, was all the time on "innovation" and the knowledge infrastructure, and not on specific industries, a technology, or institutional reform. What can be learned about innovation when comparing across industries, across technologies, across nations? How can one disentangle intellectually the complexities of the interactions involved?
The Brazilian Technology Agency (FINEPE) and the State Science Agency of Rio de Janiero (FABERJ), represented by their scientific directors, have invited "Triple Helix III: Relations Among Social, Economic, and Scientific Development" to Rio de Janiero in April 2000, to be preceded by a regional meeting in 1999. This outcome was among the consequences of a plenary discussion where policy models and theoretical models were confronted.
Angela Uller, director of COPPETEC at the Federal University of Rio de Janeiro, explained how the unit has become involved in community work. Residents of low-income "favelas" are invited to the university to assist in organizing cooperatives, taking a new role in the formation of low-tech service businesses. The industrial relations arm of the university, utilizing the interface skills gained by linking academic researchers to industry, brings these resources to bear in a creative way to address social problems, going well beyond its original official mission. The example has since become a model for a Brazilian national program.
In this same panel, Rikard Stankievicz (Lund University, Sweden) and
Richard Hull (UMIST, Manchester, UK) discussed evolutionary and network
models for understanding the implied changes in the concept of engineering
sciences in these new social contexts, the different role of the state
and local governments in organizing such niches, etc. Jean-Eric Aubert
(OECD, Paris) intervened from the audience with a discussion of socio-cultural
differences among nations and world regions that set the scene for the
possibility of creating bridges between academic puzzle-solving and social
problem-solving. Analyses at the level of the social system can thus be
helpful in understanding the boundaries that one may seek to overcome.
Is Technology a Celebration of Community?
A special session organized by the New York Academy of Sciences in New York City focused on the potential for high-tech development in the metropolitan region. At the meeting, James Hayward, President and CEO of Collaborative Laboratories Inc., submitted that "technology is a celebration of community." The multicultural environment of the metropolitan area makes it urgent to study communities as the social constructions needed to move technologies forward. Community as the basis of communication can no longer be taken for granted. As far as one may be able to communicate across otherwise dividing lines, one is able to find new solutions to old problems, and thus to improve on modes of production in terms of using resources (including human capital) in a more sustainable way.
The social shaping of technology has increasingly become an optimalization problem given dynamic market constraints: how can niches be sustained in which technologies can be nourished as a communal goal? How can human capital be made available at the right place and the right time given the complexities of the dynamics involved? What is the role of universities, of industry, of local governments, and of large research facilities in localizing inputs made available by higher-order dynamics such as global changes, intergovernmental organizations, technological developments, and multi-national corporations?
The Triple Helix thesis implies that the paradigm of research in innovation studies has definitively incorporated a network mode including uncertain relations with a plurality of environments. The helices contain communication processes which select on the interactive dynamics perceived at their borders using their respective codes to provide the new information with specific meanings. The different codes can be shared at the interfaces, and sometimes a transient arrangement can be institutionalized. Niches for knowledge-intensive industries are thus created and sustained.
From the evolutionary perspective, R&D and invention can be considered as institutionalized sources of variation, that is, as purposeful attempts at reflexive reconstruction. This variation is selected on market places on the basis of different systems of innovation. Markets may be local or global, and innovation systems may be public or private, regional or transnational. This complex system can no longer be fully understood from a single angle, since each perspective tends to stabilize another reflection. The systems under study are interactive and therefore transient and understandable only in terms of fluxes.
This "Mode 2" of innovation networks (cf. Gibbons et al. 1994) resounds with Marx's (1848) grandiose vision of modern capitalism as a system in which "all that is solid melts into air" (Berman 1982). It deviates, however, from Marx's vision in shifting the emphasis from the concreteness of industry to the elusiveness of communication networks which can be understood only reflexively. The helices are differently combined in a phase space of possibilities, in which the systems that have previously occurred provide the trajectories on which participants will have to build when constructing their innovations.
Path-dependent trajectories are expected to collide continuously, allowing for the creation of new dynamics. Following alternation between paths, a new synthesis may emerge if a next-order level of communication can be sustained. For example, contemporary science policy in the State of Rio de Janiero was found to be an amalgam of contrasting themes derived from competing interest groups and ideologies rooted in historic, economic, and geopolitical differences (Etzkowitz et al. 1998b). The awareness among the participants of the evolving complexities has geared this system into the knowledge-intensive mode. The emerging order cannot be observed directly, yet it can be inferred on the basis of reflexive observations. The new direction focuses on the future while being rooted in the past.
Innovation is initially the result of a local interaction between scientific invention, economic diffusion, and political power. Innovation systems are expected to develop further on the basis of reflexive translations. The transformations challenge the analytical understanding as they transform the conditions of the emerging achievements. In other words: what you see is not what you get. Central concepts have to be reformulated: what counts is not the accumulation of past performance, but the resourcefulness of these assets in relation to further developments. Where industries have matured or major disciplines have been established, the question has shifted toward the issue of how to recombine on the basis of existing combinations into new configurations better equipped to meet the exigencies of tomorrow (cf. Tobias and Birrer 1998).
The local instantiations, that is, the case studies, are needed for making the inferences about reorganization possible. Observations heuristically guide further research questions. No answers can be provided unless one is willing to accept an expectation as an answer. By reorganizing on the basis of new information, one makes the institutions more informed and thus more knowledge-intensive. Furthermore, the expectation of a complex dynamics enables us to improve our understanding of path-dependency and thus perhaps to achieve a competitive vantage point. The competitive vantage point is a necessary, but not a sufficient condition for a next advantage.
The Triple Helix is not meant to mesh the different communications together into the grey semblance of a compromise, but to allow for the reflexive fine-tuning of communications with different value systems in the background. Communications are also expressions of diverse institutional traditions and manifold interests. The thematically focused opening of the communication from a variety of perspectives promotes creativity, enables us to access an increasingly knowledge-intensive economy, and thus to celebrate innovation as a vital human possibility.
* rotating first authorship. The authors' addresses are:
Loet Leydesdorff, Department of Science and Technology Dynamics, Nieuwe Achtergracht 166, 1018 WV Amsterdam, The Netherlands. E-mail: l.leydesdorff@mail.uva.nl
Henry Etzkowitz, Science Policy Institute, Social Science Division, State University of New York at Purchase, 735 Anderson Hill Road, Purchase, NY 10577-1400, USA. E-mail: spi@interport.net
We gratefully acknowledge support from the U.S. National Science Foundation, the European Commission DG XII/ IRDAC, the Fundaça~o Coppetec in Brazil, the CNRS in France, the Netherlands Graduate School for Science, Technology and Modern Culture WTMC, the State University of New York SUNY, and our respective departments.
References
Abernathy, W. J. & J. Utterback (1978). "Patterns of Industrial Innovation," Technology Review 50, 41-7.
Andersen, Esben Slot (1994). Evolutionary Economics: Post-Schumpeterian Contributions. London: Pinter.
Baeta, Adelaide Coelho (1998). "The Emerging Paradigm for Technology Learning in the Knowledge Society," Industry & Higher Education (forthcoming).
Berman, Marshall (1982). All That is Solid Melts into Air: The Experience of Modernity. New York: Simon and Schuster.
Berneman, Louis and Kathleen Denis, "Evolution of Academic-Industry Transfer in the United States," Industry and Higher Education (forthcoming).
Biggiero, Lucio (1998). "Italian Industrial Districts: A Triple Helix Pattern of Problem Solving," Industry & Higher Education (forthcoming).
Bunders, Joske F. G. and Jacqueline E. W. Broerse (1998). "The Importance of Interactive Approaches to the Innovation Process: Experiences from Europe and Bangladesh," Journal of Technology Transfer (forthcoming).
Castro, Eduardo Anselmo de, Carlos Jose Rodrigues, Fernando Nogueira, and Artur da Rosa Pires (1998). "Regional Innovation Systems - The Analysis of the Portuguese Case Based on the Triple Helix Concept." Paper presented at the Triple Helix II Conference, New York/Purchase, January 1998.
Chandler, Arthur D. (1962). Strategy and Structure. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Dosi, Giovanni (1982). "Technological Paradigms and Technological Trajectories: A Suggested Interpretation of the Determinants and Directions of Technical Change," Research Policy 11, 147-62.
Eto, Manabu (1998), "New Types of Cooperative Research in Japan," Industry & Higher Education (forthcoming).
Etzkowitz, Henry (1994b). "Academic-Industry Relations: A Sociological Paradigm for Economic Development," pp. 139-51 in: Leydesdorff & Van den Besselaar (1994).
Etzkowitz, Henry and Loet Leydesdorff (eds.) (1997). Universities in the Global Economy: A Triple Helix of University-Industry-Government Relations.
London: Cassell Academic.
Etzkowitz, Henry, Andrew Webster, and Peter Healey (1998a). Capitalizing Knowledge: the Intersection of Industry and Academia. Albany: State University of New York Press.
Etzkowitz, Henry, José de Mello, Branca Terra (1998b), "When Path-dependencies Collide: The Evolution of Innovation Policy in the State of Rio de Janeiro — Brazil," Science & Public Policy (this issue).
Ferraro, Fabrizio and Mario Borroi (1998). "The Emerging Landscape of Research: Dynamics of Trust and Cooperation in University-Industry Relations." Paper presented at the Triple Helix II Conference, New York/Purchase, January 1998.
Freeman, Christopher, and Carlota Perez (1988). "Structural crises of adjustment, business cycles and investment behaviour," pp. 38-66 in: Giovanni Dosi, Chistopher Freeman, Richard Nelson, Gerald Silverberg, and Luc Soete (eds.), Technical Change and Economic Theory. London: Pinter.
Frenken, Koen (1998). "Statistical Modelling of the Triple Helix Using Complex Systems Theory." Paper presented at the Triple Helix II Conference, New York/Purchase, January 1995.
Galbraith, John Kenneth (1967). The New Industrial State. New York: The New American Library.
Galbraith, Jay R. and Daniel. A. Nathanson (1978). Strategy Implementation: The Role of Structure and Process. St. Paul: West Publishing.
Gebhardt, Christiane (1997). Die Regionalisierung von Innovationsprozessen in der Informationstechnologie. Wiesbaden: Deutscher Universitätsverlag.
Gibbons, Michael, Camille Limoges, Helga Nowotny, Simon Schwartzman, Peter Scott, and Martin Trow (1994). The new production of knowledge: the dynamics of science and research in contemporary societies. London, etc.: Sage.
Giddens, Anthony (1984). The Constitution of Society. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Gulbrandsen, Magnus (1997). "Universities and Industrial Competitive Advantage", pp. 121-31 in: Etzkowitz and Leydesdorff (1997).
Gulbrandsen, Magnus and Henry Etzkowitz (1998). "The Convergence Between Europe and America: The transition from industrial to innovation policy," Journal of Technology Transfer (forthcoming).
Hull, Richard, Vivien Walsh, Ken Green, and Andy McMeekin (1998). "The Techno-Economic: Perspectives for Analysis and Intervention, Journal of Technology Transfer (forthcoming).
Kauffman, Stuart A. (1993). Origins of Order: Self-Organization and Selection in Evolution. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Langton, Christopher G. (ed.) (1989). Artificial Life. Redwood City, CA: Addison Wesley.
Latour, Bruno (1987). Science in Action. Milton Keynes: Open University Press.
Leydesdorff, Loet (1997). "The New Communication Regime of University-Industry-Government Relations," pp. 106-117 in: Etzkowitz and Leydesdorff (1997).
Leydesdorff, Loet (1998). "Does the Triple Helix Metaphor Provide Us with an Evolutionary Model?" Paper presented at the Triple Helix II Conference, New York/Purchase, January 1998.
Leydesdorff, Loet, and Henry Etzkowitz (1996). "Emergence of a Triple Helix of University-Industry-Government Relations," Science and Public Policy 23, 279-86.
Leydesdorff Loet, and Peter Van den Besselaar (eds.) (1994). Evolutionary Economics and Chaos Theory: New Directions in Technology Studies. London: Pinter.
Leydesdorff, Loet and Peter Van den Besselaar (1997). "Scientometrics and Communication Theory: Towards Theoretically Informed Indicators," Scientometrics 38 (1), 155-74.
Luhmann, Niklas (1990). Die Wissenschaft der Gesellschaft. Frankfurt a.M.: Suhrkamp.
Lundvall, Bengt-Åke (Ed.) (1992). National Systems of Innovation. London: Pinter.
Marx, Karl ([1848], 1967). The Communist Manifesto, translated by Samuel Moore in 1888. Harmondsworth: Penguin.
McKelvey, Maureen (1997). "Emerging Environments in Biotechnology," pp. 60-70 in: Etzkowitz & Leydesdorff (1997).
Nelson, Richard R. (1994). "Economic Growth via the Coevolution of Technology and Institutions," pp. 21-32 in: Leydesdorff & Van den Besselaar (1994).
Nelson, Richard R. (ed.), (1993). National Innovation Systems: A comparative study. New York, Oxford University Press.
Nelson, Richard R. (1998). "The Entrepreneurial University: Whether, Whither, Wither?" Keynote address, Triple Helix II Conference, New York/Purchase, January 1998.
Nelson, Richard R. and Sidney G. Winter (1982). An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, Mass., Belknap Press.
Noble, David (1977). America by Design. New York: Knopf.
Nowak, Michael J. and Charles E. Grantham (1998). "The Virtual Incubator: Managing Human Capital in the Software Industry." Paper presented at the Triple Helix II Conference, New York/Purchase, January 1998.
Pires, Artur da Rosa and Eduardo Anselmo de Castro (1997). "Can a strategic project for a university be strategic to regional development?", Science and Public Policy 24 (1) 15-20
Rip, Arie and Barend van der Meulen (1996). "The Post-Modern Research System," Science and Public Policy 23 (6), 343-352.
Tong, Jian (1996). "Reflections on Human Capital Theory and Niche Theory in Evolutionary Economics." Paper at the Triple Helix Conference, Amsterdam 1996.
Turpin, Tim and Sam Garrett-Jones (1997). "Innovation Networks in Australia and China," pp. 33-46 in: Etzkowitz & Leydesdorff (1997).
Van den Belt, Henk and Arie Rip (1987). "The Nelson-Winter-Dosi model and synthetic dye chemistry," pp. 135-58 in: Wiebe Bijker, Thomas P. Hughes, and Trevor Pinch, (eds.), The Social Construction of Technological Systems. Cambridge, MA: MIT.